Liberalism: from Philosophers to Society? - By Martin Prior

Liberalism: from Philosophers to Society?

In my last article, Liberalism: from Philosophers to Politicians, I discussed a dozen or so writers on freedom/liberalism, from Lao-Tze (6th century BC) to Isaiah Berlin.  Strands of economic and socialism crept in, with Adam Smith seen as the father of economic liberalism, and John Stuart Mill the father of social liberalism.  To my mind there is not so much a dichotomy as a triplet, with civic liberalism often, as with the LibDems, ambiguous between the other two.

In fact, social liberalism is not merely non-economic liberalism: it must identify the social freedoms that economic liberalism violates.  In this paper I shall examine philosophers from the 'alleged' social liberal John Stuart Mill, to the 'alleged' libertarian socialist Noam Chomsky.  I shall then briefly discuss how liberalism and conservatism differ when adopted by the ruling classes: basically conservatives appear more progressive when empire or sphere of influence is expanding, and liberals appear more progressive when this is contracting.

As I said in my last paper, John Stuart Mill’s (England, 1806-1873) liberalism coincided with the shift from Whigs to Liberals round 1868, and most of the period of Gladstone’s first of four Liberal Governments.  He is said to be an early champion of this new Liberalism.  But he was very much a utilitarian, and believed in the pursuit of happiness as the ‘highest normative principle’ rather than a right.  Thus he was a utilitarian as well as being considered the founder of ‘Social Liberalism’ and accepted state intervention if there were sufficient utilitarian grounds.  We thus see a marriage of utilitarianism and a concept of social liberalism.

Thorstein Veblen (US, 1857–1926) was born roughly at the start of Mills’ last 15 years.  He was influential to those in America who saw liberalism as seeking a rational basis for the economy above competition and seeking of monopoly power.  His central argument was that individuals required non-economic time to become educated individuals.  This development of liberalism to transcend the economic was parallelled by Isaiah Berlin (Latvia/United Kingdom, 1909–1997), famous for distinguishing two concepts of liberty 'positive' and 'negative' liberty which he saw as mutually opposing concepts.  Positive liberty arouse through state power to ‘liberate’ humankind from its worst aspects and was in danger of sliding into totalitarianism.  On the other hand, negative liberty required that individuals were given maximal freedom from external constraints, as long as the like rights of others were not violated.

These last two are important in the development of the social factors in liberalism, but just as Adam Smith had added formalism to economic liberalism, so did the UK Liberal John Maynard Keynes for Keynesian economics, which was critical for developing new attitudes in attacking the Great Depression.  Those who attacking present-day austerity cite Keynes, and show how Obama’s policies are working, just as Roosevelt’s did.

Countering Keynes are Friedrich Hayek and Milton Friedman, who developed neo-liberalism, which has crept into much modern economic thinking.  It had disastrous results in Chile, which was set up as a flagship under the then military junta, which eventually abandoned much of  the thinking of Friedman’s ‘Chicago Boys’, Chileans who had studied under Friedman in Chicago.

The prolific works of Noam Chomsky (USA, 1928- , linguist and philosopher) give a day-to-day and blow-by-blow account of neo-colonialism.

Now I have shown how ‘liberalism’ can mask conflicting attitudes of the social and economic liberals.  But the term social liberalism has been adopted by many in the centre and centre-right, such as John Major.  In fact we note from wikipedia that:

“Social liberalism seeks to balance individual freedom and social justice.  Like classical liberalism, it endorses a market economy[my italics] and the expansion of civil and political rights and liberties, but differs in that it believes the legitimate role of the government includes addressing economic and social issues such as poverty, health care and education.”

To my mind, endorsing a market economy is neither social liberal nor indeed utilitarian; John Stuart Mill had nothing significant to say about the market.  But in fact not only is the market an imperfect tool for social objectives.  It is not even an optimal tool in terms of economic efficiency.  Thus:

(i)            The optimum sum of profits is not the same as the sum of optimum profits across companies: this is particularly noticeable in the drive to oligopoly and monopoly.

(ii)          The optimum sum of profits is not the same as the sum of optimum profits across regions: in my view, though it is yet to become an important strand of economic thinking, wealth tends to gravitate towards an economic centre of gravity, something which increasingly afflicts the EU.  And of course quite notoriously the North-South Divide is notoriously inefficient for its inequalities.

(iii)         The optimum sum of profits is not the same as the sum of optimum profits across time: this is most notable in the tendency of enterprises to exploit resources to extinction.  The air, water, animals (for example fish) and in many ways, not least humans.

If I had a wider economic brief here I would discuss ways of addressing these problems.  But in the writings of Raymond Plant (UK, 1945-), political philosopher and Labour Peer writes extensively about neo-liberalism.  According to John Gray’s review (in the New Statesman) of Plant’s Neoliberal State, “Plant's central charge against neoliberalism is that, when stated clearly, it falls apart and is finally indistinguishable from a mild form of social democracy.”  I can say no more.

When we move from philosophies to politics, we move into an area where I believe we must look into the political adherents’ motivations in terms of their part in patterns of exploitation.  And in the developed countries, this really means thieves squabbling over the booty from exploitation of the Third World.  This issue is in no way addressed by social marketers and mainstream social democrats.

So regardless of the self-image of liberals and conservatives, I shall briefly express their behaviour in practice among leading world powers. The liberals value and develop their skills, and are quite ready to create empires and ‘neo-colonies’, which take advantage of their targets’ ignorance and often fear.  The Tories’ approach, with whom conservatism is an asset, is frighten would-be supporters into loyalty, playing on ignorance and fear.  This rather than technology is their power base, but despite its shaky nature, they will resort to force against their opponents rather than persuasion.

Martin Prior


The Philosophy Takeaway Issue 51 'Open Topic'

Want to write for us?

If you would like to submit an article for consideration, please contact thephilosophytakeaway@gmail.com

Search This Blog